You are viewing a read-only archive of the Blogs.Harvard network. Learn more.

[This is a heavily edited transcript of a talk that I gave on January 3, 2013, at a panel on open access at the 87th Annual Meeting of the Linguistic Society of America (LSA, the main scholarly society for linguistics, and publisher of the journal Language), co-sponsored by the Modern Language Association (MLA).]


Thank you for this opportunity to join the others on this panel in talking about open access. I will concentrate in particular on the relationship between open access and the future of scholarly societies. I’m thinking in particular of small to medium scholarly societies, which have small publishing programs that are often central to the solvency of the societies and to their ability to do the important work that they do. In one sense it should be obvious, and I think it’s been made obvious by the previous speakers, that open access meshes well with the missions of scholarly societies. LSA’s mission, for instance, is “to advance the scientific study of language. LSA plays a critical role in supporting and disseminating linguistic scholarship both to professional linguists and to the general public.” [Emphasis added.] So I’ll just assume the societal benefit of open access to researchers and to the general public alike. For the purpose of conversation let’s just take that as given.

Nonetheless, many scholarly societies, and the faculty that support them, are worried that open access – at least as they understand the concept – could exacerbate the serious financial distress that many of those societies are already under, and even undermine their very existence and thereby their ability to carry out this mission. I’ve heard faculty worry that even “green” open access (self-archiving of articles in open-access repositories) could undermine the economics of journal publishing in such a way that their scholarly societies could be endangered.

I want to argue that there is a real threat that many scholarly societies accurately perceive in their publishing programs, but that we must be careful not to misdiagnose this problem. In fact, a general move to open access would be the best outcome for scholarly society publishers. If the entirety of journal publishing magically metamorphosed somehow to an open-access system, scholarly society publishers would be much better off. From a strategic point of view then, the best course of action for scholarly societies and for the faculty and researchers who support them would be to promote a shift to open access as widely and as quickly as possible. Now, the threat that societies perceive is an economic threat, so my remarks will be almost entirely economic in nature; I’m just warning you. My talk certainly will have no linguistic import at all.

Economic properties of the subscription market

Let me turn first to some basic truths about the subscription journal market that I’ve come to realize are important in understanding what the underlying economic issues are.

Journal access is a complementary good

The first is that different journals — viewed as products, as goods being sold — are in economists’ terms complements, not substitutes. Substitute goods are products like Coke and Pepsi. If you have one it decreases the value of the other to you, as they fulfill similar functions. Complements are products like a left shoe and a right shoe – that’s the most extreme case. If you have one it increases the value to you of the other. There are less extreme cases of economic complements – printers and toner cartridges, peanut butter and jelly, pencils and erasers.

What about scholarly journals? Suppose you’re a patron of a library that subscribes to a bundle of, let’s say, Elsevier journals, including the journal Lingua. Does the library subscription to that journal make you more or less interested in reading, say, Language? (We’re holding cost aside. When thinking about complements or substitutes, it’s just about the value to the consumer, not the cost.) Of course, you’re not less inclined to read Language just because the library subscribes to Lingua. In fact you may be more inclined, because some Lingua articles will cite Language articles. You read the Lingua article, you want to to read the Language article it cites. So that would lead you to track down those articles and read them if the library had a subscription. And vice versa: a subscription to Language can increase the value of a subscription to Lingua. So journals are economic complements, not substitutes.

Inefficiency in the subscription market

This has important ramifications. Non-substitutive goods don’t compete against each other and complementary goods in fact support each other in the market. If consumers suddenly buy a lot more Coke, Pepsi is worried. But if peanut butter sales skyrocket, the jelly manufacturers are elated. So the complementary subscription of individual journals means that there’s limited market competition between journals, and limited competition leads to inefficiency in the journal market. (That’s not to say that there isn’t competition between publishers. But as we’ll see, the primary form of that competition is in competing to acquire journals.)


Average journal prices in a range of fields, differentiated by commercial and non-profit publishers. Left is based on prices as dollars per page. Right is based on dollars per citation, to normalize for quality. Data are from Bergstrom and Bergstrom, Journal pricing across disciplines, 2002.
Figure 1: Average journal prices in a range of fields, differentiated by commercial and non-profit publishers. Left is based on prices as dollars per page. Right is based on dollars per citation, to normalize for quality. Data are from Bergstrom and Bergstrom, Journal pricing across disciplines, 2002.

We can see ample evidence of this kind of inefficiency. One clear form of evidence for inefficiency is wide price disparities. The graph in Figure 1 shows average journal prices in a whole range of fields. The data is from a study by Bergstrom and Bergstrom, and they differentiated the cost of the journals by whether the publisher is commercial or non-profit. The dark blue represents the commercial publishers, the light blue the nonprofit publishers. Notice that the commercial publishers on average charge about five times more for their journals than non-profit publishers, as measured by price per page. Now you might think there is a good explanation for this disparity: perhaps these aren’t comparable products. Perhaps the commercial publishers are selling a much better product, higher quality journals, and it’s therefore more expensive to develop them, and that’s what accounts for the price differential. So we can normalize for that by using a proxy for quality. One widely used proxy for quality, admittedly not a great one but at least widely touted by journals themselves through the ubiquitous “Impact Factor”, is the number of citations the journal receives. The second graph in Figure 1 thus shows price per citation. Measured this way, commercial journals are fifteen times more expensive than non-profit journals from the same field. Now, linguistics was not one of the fields examined in this study. But the same holds true here as well. For example, the subscription rate for LSA’s journal Language, published by a non-profit of course, is $3.31 per citation, whereas Elsevier’s Lingua is $32.30 per citation – almost exactly ten times more expensive.

This kind of price differential is a clear sign of market failure, especially as it has been sustained over decades. You just do not get this kind of price disparity preserved over long periods of time in well functioning markets. Go to the various grocery stores in your neighborhood and see if you can find apples at different grocery stores at a price differential of a factor of ten. It does not happen. Such price disparities are a clear sign of inefficiency.

Journal access is a monopolistic good


Elsevier revenues, profit, and profit margin, 2002–2011. Data are from Mike Taylor, The obscene profits of commercial scholarly publishers, 2012.
Figure 2: Elsevier revenues, profit, and profit margin, 2002–2011. Data are from Mike Taylor, The obscene profits of commercial scholarly publishers, 2012.

The second basic truth is that the good being sold in the subscription market is access, and access is a monopolistic good. The monopoly is enabled by copyright, founded in the government’s ability as codified in Article I Section 8 of the Constitution to provide an exclusive right to the creator of a work for a limited period of time. Subscription publishers acquire exclusive rights to the articles they publish — typically by acquiring copyright, sometimes by acquiring an exclusive license, which is a distinction without a difference — and this allows publishers in theory and in many cases in practice to extract monopoly rents in selling access to the articles. We see evidence of this as well. For example, in Figure 2, I show a graph of the revenues, profits, and most importantly the profit margin, for the publisher Elsevier over the last decade. It’s quite a good business with annual revenues of over $2 billion, but that’s not the big point. The big point is the extraordinary 35–40% profit margins. It’s not just Elsevier. Many large commercial publishers have maintained these kinds of profit margins over a long period of time. An interesting thing to look at is the steady increase in the margins even during the financial crisis starting in 2009 when, for instance, many university endowments and library budgets dropped precipitously. Harvard’s endowment went down by 30% but Elsevier did just fine, and the other large publishers as well. So maintaining those kinds of profit margins again is a sign of the ability to extract monopoly rents.

Journal access is a bundled good

The third basic truth is that pricing is controlled not at the level of the individual journal but at the level of a bundle of journals. The large publishers have portfolios of hundreds to thousands of journals. They can therefore apply prices to a bundle of journals, not a single journal. They can show vastly different prices to different buyers and use the bundles to incentivize buyers, the libraries, to pay larger fees. The upshot of this point, that pricing happens at the bundle level and not the journal level, is that a library can find it extremely difficult to control its expenditures by canceling individual journals because the publisher can just price the smaller bundle at essentially the same cost as the larger bundle.

I’ll tell you a personal story. Some years ago, Harvard was one of the first universities to cancel the “big deal” with Elsevier. I don’t want to pick on Elsevier. They’re not bad people. They’re a wonderful group of folks. Lots of the large publishers of journals work this way and it’s not because they’re evil or anything like that. I just mention the Elsevier case as a convenient story. Harvard was one of the first universities to cancel its “big deal” and went a la carte on the journals. In the School of Engineering and Applied Sciences, my own school, we had been subscribing to around 130 Elsevier journals in engineering and applied sciences as I recall. We took the opportunity to cancel about 100 of these journals, leaving something like 30 journals, hoping to recoup some costs. And we did. The first year we recouped about 20%. The following year the total cost was back where it had been before the cancellations, and it has increased steadily from there. From the library’s point of view, you can’t win by canceling journals, because the product is not the journal, it’s the bundle.

Edlin and Rubinfeld, in a Law Review article about possible anti-trust implications of this bundling, say “The immediate effect of [bundled pricing] has been to move competition from individual journals to large bundles of journals. … Creating a large bundle of journals to compete with Elsevier or Kluwer seems almost insurmountable. … There are indications that [bundled pricing] is hindering entry. Librarians … say that they would spend more money for journals from smaller and alternative publishers if they could achieve proportionate savings from reductions. By selling electronic bundles, publishers have erected a strategic barrier to entry at just the time that the electronic publishing possibility has made it increasingly possible for alternative publishers to overcome the existing structural barriers.” The fact that competition is at the level of bundles, not at the level of journals, is very important.

The result: market dysfunction


Scholarly journal expenditures percentage increase 1986–2010 compared to consumer price index. Data from Association for Research Libraries.
Figure 3: Scholarly journal expenditures percentage increase 1986–2010 compared to consumer price index. Data from Association for Research Libraries.

When we put all these properties of the journal market together, the end result is market dysfunction and a steady long-term hyperinflation in journal expenditures by libraries. Figure 3 shows a graph of serials expenditures over the last couple of decades, the dark blue line. The light blue line is the consumer price index, a proxy for the ambient rate of inflation. You can see that serials expenditures in research libraries have been going up at something like three times the rate of inflation for decades. Exponential real growth in the cost of journals is an unsustainable state of affairs.

I return to the issue of inefficiency. Why is it that the non-profit publishers are so much more efficient than the commercial publishers? Not in every case of course but on average the difference is really striking. There are a couple of possible reasons. One is that the non-profits tend to be scholarly societies who may be motivated not by profit maximization but by service to the field. I think that’s true to a certain extent. But also the non-profits tend to be small publishers with few journals – maybe one, two, three, five, ten journals. Since bundle size governs market power, non-profits have less ability to grow margins. And scholarly societies rightly complain that they’re being squeezed. From the point of view of libraries, if you have to cancel something you can recoup revenue if you cancel the journals from a small publisher. You can’t recoup revenue if you cancel journals from the large commercial publishers. As a library, what are you going to do? Cancel scholarly society journals, just as the societies have been rightly complaining about.

But notice that the problem that scholarly societies face, a problem that will only increase in a status quo future, is based not on open access but on inherent properties of the subscription market that they participate in. For scholarly societies, the status quo is not a good alternative. Doing nothing is a failing strategy.

Open-access journals as a preferable system

The idea of open-access journals is that they provide access to the articles for free. How can this be a better system for scholarly societies, given that much of the societies’ revenues may come from the publishing program?

Open-access journals don’t charge for access, but that doesn’t mean they eschew revenue entirely. Open-access journals are just selling a different good, and therefore participating in a different market. Instead of selling access to readers (or the readers’ proxy, the libraries), they sell publisher services to the authors (or to the authors’ proxy, their research funders).

In fact there are now over 8,500 open-access journals listed in the Directory of Open Access Journals. Some of them have been mentioned already on this panel: Linguistic Discovery, Semantics and Pragmatics. The majority of existing open-access journals, like those journals, don’t charge author-side article-processing charges (APCs). But in the end APCs seems to me the most reasonable, reliable, scalable, and efficient revenue mechanism for open-access journals. This move from reader-side subscription fees to author-side APCs has dramatic ramifications for the structure of the market that the publisher participates in.

Economic properties of the open-access journal market

The open-access APC market has quite different properties from the subscription market. Recall the basic truths about the subscription market. Journals are complements, not substitutes. There’s limited market competition. The product being sold is a monopolistic good. Pricing is controlled at the bundle level. What are the corresponding properties of the publisher services market, the market that open-access journals participate in? In that market, the purchaser of the good is the author or the author’s proxy, not the reader or reader’s proxy. And from the point of view of an author, two journals are not complements but substitutes. You can publish your article in the Journal of Linguistics or Lingua or better yet in Language. But having published it in one, you have no incentive to publish it in the other. In fact, you’re not allowed to publish in both, making journals perfect substitutes. There is no value to the second journal once you’ve published the article in the first journal, from the point of view of the author trying to get a publication.

So journals compete for authors in a way they don’t for readers, and this competition leads to much greater efficiency. Open-access publishers are highly motivated to provide better services at lower price to compete for authors’ article submissions. We actually see evidence of this competition on both price and quality happening in the market. I won’t go through examples but have written about it previously.

Second, publisher services on the author side are not a monopolistic good. Anyone can provide those services. In fact because the service is a knowledge good, there are exceptionally low barriers to entry. Kai von Fintel and David Beaver can just unilaterally set up Semantics and Pragmatics; maybe they’ll be successful and maybe they won’t. In this case, it turned out pretty well. The low barrier to entry further enhances competition and improves the efficiency of the market.

Finally, pricing is controlled not at the level of the bundle of journals. You don’t care about the bundle of the publisher when you’re an author submitting to a journal. You care about the journal. Actually, pricing is not even at the journal level, but at the level of the individual article. So price competition happens at that level as well, with journals competing for individual articles on price as well as quality.

In summary, the open-access APC market is a more efficient market than the closed-access subscription market for reasons of basic economics. That’s not just my opinion. Claudio Aspesi, senior analyst at Sanford Bernstein studying the finances of publishing companies, has estimated that a transition to open access would lead to Elsevier cutting its margins by 41–89%.

Comparative cost of open-access journals

Let me say something about the overall cost for the two kinds of models. The APCs that open-access journals charge range from $0 to around $3,000. The median turns out to be zero. But for those open-access journals that do charge a fee, the mean is around $1,200, and reasonable sustainable fees seem to be shaking out in the $1,000 to $1,500 range. Let’s call it $1,500. Since article processing fees are essentially the totality of revenue that open-access journals receive, the APC is a reasonable figure for average revenue per article. There are open-access publishers who are profitable in that range, including commercial open-access journals.

What’s the corresponding number for subscription journals? What is their average revenue per article? The Scholarly Publishing Roundtable reported total 2008 revenue for scholarly publishing at $8 billion on 1.5 million articles, the vast bulk of that revenue coming from subscription fees. Average revenue per article for subscription journals is, by that measure, over $5,000 an article. Remember that this averages over all of the journals — the high quality and the low alike.

So what’s happening is that authors one way or another are paying. Either you’re paying an APC to an open-access journal or you’re paying with your copyright to a subscription journal, which the publisher then monetizes, turning it into about $5,000 per article. It turns out that if we moved from a subscription journal world to an open-access world, the institutions of the world would go from paying, on average, $5,000 an article to about $1,500. Let’s suppose the $1,500 estimate is unreasonably low. Let’s suppose that really the average APC would be what the most high-end open-access journal, PLoS Biology, now charges – that’s $2,900; call it $3,000. If every article moved from the subscription model to an open-access APC model at the high end of cost – we would still be saving 40%. And more importantly, we would be better executing the scholarly society mission by providing the broadest possible dissemination.

Scholarly societies as open-access publishers

Who wins in this kind of market – a non-monopolistic, competitive market of substitutes where the processing fees are considerably less than the current cost per article for subscription journals? The publisher who wins in that market is the publisher who can provide the best services, including imprimatur, at the lowest price to the author, that is, the publisher who is most efficient. Scholarly society publishers would have a huge lead in this market, because they are manifestly more efficient than commercial publishers by a large factor. If the scholarly journal market were structured as the open-access journal market rather than the subscription journal market, scholarly society publishers would be the big winners. And scholarly societies are beginning to realize that open access could be a boon not only to their mission – that much should be uncontroversial – but also to their solvency. Perhaps for this reason, some 600 scholarly societies, including the LSA, are already publishing open-access journals.

At the root, the reason that scholarly societies benefit from playing in the open-access APC market rather than the closed-access subscription fee market is the difference in the goods being sold. When the good is a journal bundle, the companies with the biggest bundles, the large commercial publishers, win. When the good is publisher services for an individual article, the publishers that can deliver those services for an individual article most efficiently, the non-profit publishers, win. Sure, there are economies of scale, but empirical evidence shows that the scholarly societies are already far better able to efficiently deliver services despite any scale disadvantage.

The problem for open access: the transition

Now, all that sounds great, but I don’t want to be too positive. As I said at the outset, there is a real worry that society publishers should have about the open-access APC market. But it’s not that they’d be at a competitive disadvantage in that market; I think that they’d have a huge advantage. And it’s important to remember that they’re already at a huge disadvantage in the subscription journal market; status quo is a failing strategy. Rather the problem is this. Open-access journals are at a disadvantage in their competition for authors against subscription journals. That is, the problem arises across the two markets. When the only kind of journals are open-access journals, scholarly societies have the upper hand. When there are both kinds of journals in the market, both subscription journals and open-access journals, the open-access journals are at a competitive disadvantage because (from the author’s point of view) publishing is free in a subscription journal. (Of course, it’s not really free; it’s just that the research libraries of the world are underwriting the very high $5,000 cost per article.) By contrast, in an open-access APC journal, the author personally could be out let’s say $1,200 or $1,500 or whatever. This is a problem not just for scholarly societies but for all publishers exploring the possibility of going fee-based open access.

To make a transition possible, what we, as supporters of scholarly societies, should be working on is placing open-access journals on a level playing field with subscription journals. There’s a principle at stake here, and the principle is this: Dissemination of research results is an inherent part of the research process. This is something that publishers themselves are frequently pointing out — that they are part of the research process. Consequently, the funders of that research should underwrite dissemination of the results. Who are the funders of the research? In science, technology, and medicine, public and private funding agencies are the primary research funders. By this principle then, the funding agencies giving the grants in those areas would be on the hook to pay the $1,000 or $1,200 or $1,500 or $2,900 publication fees. Most funding agencies already will pay for publication costs for open-access journals (though not in an ideal way, which I’ve written about in the past). What about fields where there aren’t funding agencies handing out large grants? In the humanities and social sciences, universities are the de facto primary research funders. Faculty members in universities are doing research in those fields as part of their employment as researchers. As the primary research funders in the humanities and social sciences, in linguistics in particular, the universities that employ us should be on the hook to disseminate the research results that their researchers generate.

This is the principle behind an effort called the Compact for Open-Access Publishing Equity. It was set up by a group of five universities initially — Cornell, Dartmouth, Harvard, MIT, and Berkeley — to place the open-access revenue model on a more level playing field with the subscription model. Since then another dozen or so institutions have signed on. The Compact says that these universities commit to providing a mechanism for underwriting reasonable publication fees for articles written by their faculty and published in fee-based open-access journals. From the point of view of these signatory institutions, and the many other institutions that don’t happen to be signatories but have similar funding policies, if you structure your journal as an open-access journal charging a publication fee, you don’t need to worry that the authors will be personally out of pocket to pay those fees; the university will pay on their behalf.

Next steps

Given that the open-access publication fee market would be preferable from the point of view of scholarly societies and their members, what should scholarly societies be doing from the strategic point of view? What is in the best interest of us as supporters of scholarly societies? Happily the best interest of scholarly society publishers is the best interest of the scholars themselves, namely as rapid a transition to open access as possible. So scholarly societies should be doing what they can to speed that transition, and I’m glad to say that the LSA and the MLA are working in that direction. I wish all scholarly societies would do so as well.

Of course, the ideal action for a scholarly society is to convert all of its journals to open access. By doing so, they help set expectations among authors that we don’t restrict access to articles, thereby hastening the day that closed-access journals find it impossible to compete for authors.

But some scholarly societies may still find it too worrisome to take such a bold move, not because they disagree with my conclusion that they fare better in an open access world, but because they fear not making it through the transition to that world. I’m sympathetic to that worry. Still, there are important actions that societies can take short of converting all of their journals to open access, actions that will still greatly contribute to changing the expectations of scholars that research results should be and are being made accessible. Scholarly societies can:

  • Experiment with open access for at least some of their journals (as LSA is doing with Semantics and Pragmatics), thereby gaining exactly the experience with open-access publishing that will be invaluable in the future.
  • Along the same lines, commit to open access for any new journals.
  • For the legacy non-open-access journals, provide delayed open-access to articles, making them available with a broad license after, say, six months or one year. The LSA has already taken this important step. Once conditions are right, the delay can simply be dropped.
  • Explicitly allow self-archiving of articles published in their journals, the green open access that I alluded to at the start of the talk. Doing so sends a strong signal that the society supports open access. At the same time, there is “no persuasive evidence that increased access threatens the sustainability of traditional subscription-supported journals, or their ability to fund rigorous peer review.” TheLSA does this, and the MLA recently announced that they are modifying their publication agreement along these lines, and even allowing distribution of the final published version after one year.
  • Recognize, accommodate, and promote university and funder open-access policies. Accommodation requires only the addition of a single sentence to a publisher’s publication agreement. The pertinent sentence taken from the Science Commons addenda is this:

    Where applicable, Publisher acknowledges that Author’s assignment of copyright or Author’s grant of exclusive rights in the Publication Agreement is subject to Author’s prior grant of a non-exclusive copyright license to Author’s employing institution and/or to a funding entity that financially supported the research reflected in the Article as part of an agreement between Author or Author’s employing institution and such funding entity, such as an agency of the United States government.

    (My guess is that it should be possible to generate an English version of such a sentence as well.)

  • Support pro-open-access legislation such as the Federal Research Public Access Act. At the least, scholarly societies should disavow anti-open-access statements made on their behalf by publishing consortia, as the MLA did in its statement opposing the Research Works Act.
  • Leverage the society’s membership to push for open-access underwriting by funding agencies and by universities such as envisioned by the Compact for Open-Access Publishing Equity.

To the extent that we can get a transition to a primarily open-access publishing system to happen, scholarly societies, their members, and the general public will all be much better off, which is a happy confluence of interest. Thank you very much.

25 Responses to “Why open access is better for scholarly societies”

  1. Adam Etkin Says:

    I see one big problem with your argument, but it’s possible you’ve addressed it and I’m missing it. For small/medium sized societies who publish only the very best in their field, it would be impossible (as I see it) to maintain that level of quality. Typically the top journals in their field accept about 10% (give or take) of submitted manuscripts. The larger, successful OA publishers, PLoS is the prime example, accept 65-70% of all submissions. Their explanation that they accept research which is “sound” regardless of perceived impact on the field, sounds nice. However, I’ve yet to see an OA model which allows a journal to remain selective in what they publish that is also financially viable. The numbers just don’t add up. I suspect this is the real reason, or at least a big one, such a high percentage is accepted by the “mega” OA journals. So, societies considering a conversion to OA should consider if they are willing to sacrifice how selective they are and if this lowers the quality of their publications. If they still wish to move to OA and remain selective, then they must be confident they can make up lost revenue from some other stream beside publishing. There is NO WAY (that I see) a journal can be highly selective and survive on APC fees. There’s the rub.

  2. Stuart Shieber Says:

    First, a correction: Although PLoS ONE, PLoS’s “megajournal”, has a relatively high acceptance rate, PLoS’s flagship journals PLoS Biology and PLoS Medicine are highly selective, and their community journals are also quite selective. In fact, there are many selective OA journals that are viable on APCs, this despite the fact that (as I argued in the post) OA journals are currently at a systematic disadvantage as compared to subscription journals.

    There is nothing in principle that says that moving a journal to OA must inherently involve a reduction in selectivity to retain sustainability. The reason that OA journals can remain sustainable at high levels of selectivity — so there is no “race to the bottom” — is that journals of higher selectivity can charge higher APCs, to compensate for the opportunity cost of the APCs from rejected articles. Conversely, reducing selectivity may actually harm the finances of a journal if it reduces the journal’s ability to command high APCs. I’ve shown in a previous post that this positive correlation between selectivity and APC holds in practice. In fact, there are many high quality sustainable OA journals. The “Cost Effectiveness for Open Access Journals” visualization from eigenfactor.org provides a convenient way of exploring OA journals to find examples. And it incidentally corroborates my earlier finding of positive correlation between fee and quality.

  3. Adam Etkin Says:

    You’re correct about PLoS ONE vs. the other PLoS journals, however I still feel that without PLoS ONE, PLoS wouldn’t be financially sustainable. I will need to take a look at the links you’ve provided (thank you), but I am highly skeptical that APCs can really be raised to the level needed for an OA journal to stay afloat without a dramatic increase in acceptance rate, and that makes me very nervous.

  4. Richard Van Noorden Says:

    Re: ‘That’s not just my opinion. Claudio Aspesi, senior analyst at Sanford Bernstein studying the finances of publishing companies, has estimated that a transition to open access would lead to Elsevier cutting its margins by 41–89%.’

    OK, but be aware that other analysts don’t think the margins will drop as much as Aspesi does. You can pick his view, but you’re cherry-picking. (His view is open-access, which is everyone is citing it, I suppose!)

  5. Richard Van Noorden Says:

    Another nitpick to what is a really nice article. You cannot divide $8 billion in revenues by 1.5 million articles to conclude a cost of around $5000 per article. That is because those revenues were not gained just on ‘articles published in one year’, but on the entire set of articles to which publishers are offering libraries access.

    A bottom-up analysis of the cost-per-article for subscription journals in 2008 came out at around £2,634 ($3951 with the 1-1.5 conversion of the time, or $4154 with today’s currency exchange). http://liber.library.uu.nl/index.php/lq/article/view/8010/8350

    Anyway, still true that money should be saved with the greater efficiency of a more transparent and competitive APC market.

  6. Björn Brembs Says:

    Excellent post!
    I’d only like to add one important detail (also with respect to some of the comments above): there is no evidence backing up the notion of any inherent difference in ‘quality’ between journals. We have recently surveyed the empirical literature on the mater and at best, journal rank is not predictive of ‘quality’ if all the available metrics are taken into account. If anything, a trend can be observed that – counterintuitively – the science published in high ranking journals has a higher chance of being of ‘lesser’ quality than that published in lower ranking journals:
    http://arxiv.org/abs/1301.3748

    I think the data you present make it unambiguously clear that corporate publishers are overcharging the public purse for their services. Bibliometric data are equally unambiguous that the ranking of journals is like homeopathy, astrology or dowsing: subjectively, we might feel inclined to trust any personally experienced effects, but these effects disappear upon scientific scrutiny.

  7. Why open access is better for scholarly societies (and everyone else) › Hybrid Publishing Lab Notepad Says:

    […] Why open access is better for scholarly societies (and everyone else) Posted by CDC Admin on January 31, 2013 In Links OA, Open Access Leave a comment […]

  8. Why open access is better for scholarly societies (and everyone else) › Hybrid Publishing Lab Notepad Says:

    […] Why open access is better for scholarly societies (and everyone else) Posted by Christian Heise on January 31, 2013 In Links OA, Open Access Leave a comment […]

  9. Backfire — An Argument That OA Is Better for Non-Profit Societies Demonstrates Just the Opposite « The Scholarly Kitchen Says:

    […] Stuart Shieber, Director of the Office for Scholarly Communication at Harvard published the edited t…, in which he praised open access (OA) as a better system for learned societies. This is an […]

  10. Anna Sharman Says:

    Thanks for a very informative post, in fact the best I’ve seen yet on the economics of scholarly publishing.

    I’d like to respond to Adam Etkin’s point that “There is NO WAY (that I see) a journal can be highly selective and survive on APC fees.” There is a way: a small fee charged for all authors who submit to the journal, even if their paper is rejected (combined with APCs). Few journals use this mechanism at the moment, but for a highly selective journal it seems feasible to me. The main barrier to journals charging submission fees may be simply that none of them want to be the first to try it. I’ve reviewed the pros and cons of submission fees on my blog at https://sharmanedit.wordpress.com/2012/03/21/submission-fees/

  11. John Mark Ockerbloom Says:

    Very interesting and thought-provoking article! Though there’s one important bit where we need to talk through things a little further.

    In the “transition” section, you say

    “When there are both kinds of journals in the market, both subscription journals and open-access journals, the open-access journals are at a competitive disadvantage [from the author’s point of view].”

    But it’s not clear to me that we’re going to end up in a state where this is *not* the case. If subscription journals don’t go away altogether (and why would they, if they’re at an advantage for attracting authors, and libraries are still buying *some* things?), then open-access journals need to be viable over the long term in a mixed journal economy. Or, OA journals need to develop enough of a comparative advantage that subscription journals become a small part of the scholarly commmunications process that doesn’t threaten OA or library budgets (even if new subscription journals come along).

    I can think of some possible ways this shift in OA journal viability and attractiveness could happen, though they’re by no means sure things. We should discuss how this transition could work, because unless there are some further changes to the way scholarly communication is conducted and funded, I don’t see “all scholarly journals are open access” as a stable equilibrium.

  12. Adam Etkin Says:

    Anna, thank you for the response. Charging submission fees, in my opinion, will only result in a very small additional revenue stream. Nothing that would have a large enough impact to be sustainable long term. Also, remember this blog specifically speaks to Societies. Are organizations going to start charging submission fees on top of membership dues? Is the fee waived or reduced for members? It’s a good idea, one already in use by both NFPs and for-profit publishers, but again I do not think revenue from this area makes much of a difference.

  13. Martin Haspelmath Says:

    Very informative article, but Shieber seems to forget about one important problem: He says that “(with OA) pricing is controlled not at the level of the bundle of journals. You don’t care about the bundle of the publisher when you’re an author submitting to a journal. You care about the journal.”
    But of course commercial publishers are interested in selling OA services to authors or their proxies in bundles as well: What we’ll see increasingly is Elsevier and the like offering universities discounts on APCs if the universities pay on the basis of the number of their employees (or similar measures). Universities may feel they have to accept these offers, and in practice this may mean that if I publish in an Elsevier journal, I can do so without paying at all, whereas if I want to publish in a small nonprofit OA journal, I have to pay it out of my own research budget. So there will continue to be pressure on scholarly associations to join the big players, and they can continue to sell their journals in bundles. (For an example affecting my own institution, see http://www.degruyter.com/dg/page/75/aktuelle-presseinformationen)

  14. Matthew Cockerill Says:

    Adam,
    You raise an important point. I would argue that the OA model usefully highlights the expense and profligacy involved in running a high-calibre journal which rejects 90% of all articles, if nothing is done to ensure that an outlet exists for the significant subset of the rejected articles which are scientifically sound and (after suitable revision) suitable for publication, just not in the highest-ranked journal.

    BioMed Central helps societies to efficiently manage transfer of a subset of rejected articles (including the peer review reports) from their high rejection rate titles, for consideration by more inclusive sister titles. This provides an improved experience for authors, makes more efficient use of reviewer and editor time, and ensures that the economics of open access publication work for the society and the publisher, even in the case of high rejection-rate flagship journals.

  15. Audit Board, Lords Open Access, Council and BioIndustry | Professor Douglas Kell's blog Says:

    […] is a lot of stuff going on in OA right now. Here are two (one, two) more or less wildly contrasting views, albeit driven by differing objective functions. One […]

  16. » Why open access is better for scholarly societies The Occasional Pamphlet | Flexibility Enables Learning Says:

    […] on blogs.law.harvard.edu Like this:LikeBe the first to like this. PermalinkLeave a […]

  17. Открытый доступ как новая модель в науке и образовании | Теплица Социальных Технологий (ТеСТ) | Краудсорсинг, технологии для третьего секто Says:

    […] своем выступлении на панели по открытому доступу на «87th Annual Meeting of the […]

  18. Nicht einmal Harvard kann sich noch alle akademischen Veröffentlichungen leisten — neunetz.com Says:

    […] 1996 and 2010, journal subscription prices rose at four times the rate of inflation. The result is that each published paper now costs the academic world more than $5000. Prices are […]

  19. Publishing and the POOC, or, why we need open access Says:

    […] The Occasional Pamphlet on scholarly communication […]

  20. Publishing and the POOC, or, why we need open access - JustPublics@365 Says:

    […] Elsevier clears more profit than Walmart, Apple, and Disney. Data from Mike Taylor, The obscene profits of commercial scholarly publishers, 2012. Chart by Stuart Shieber, 2013. […]

  21. E-Lert # 509 / Cyberavis numéro 509 – E-lert @ Cyber-avis Says:

    […] Why open access is better for scholarly societies […]

  22. Publishing and the POOC, or, why we need open access Says:

    […] Elsevier clears more profit than Walmart, Apple, and Disney. Data are from Mike Taylor, The obscene profits of commercial scholarly publishers, 2012. Chart by Stuart Shieber, 2013. […]

  23. Moshe Vardi Says:

    ” As a library, what are you going to do? Cancel scholarly society journals, just as the societies have been rightly complaining about.”

    Stuart, do you have data to back this claim? Are society journals really under stress more than commercial journals? From what I see with ACM the pressure comes from members, not from libraries.

  24. Why open-access publication should be nonprofit | Wissen & Schaffen Says:

    […] S. (2013). Why Open Access is Better for Scholarly Societies. Available online at: http://blogs.law.harvard.edu/pamphlet/2013/01/29/why-open-access-is-better-for-scholarly-societies/ Share this:TwitterFacebookLike this:Like […]

  25. The Cost of Scientific Publishing — Banyan Blog Says:

    […] at an artificially high rate. In fact, between 1996 and 2010, journal subscription prices rose at three times the rate of inflation. This exponential jump in price is not sustainable for their […]